Peer-reviewed articles The price of opulence On a constellation of interests in the European market for natural gas

This article discusses the reaction of the EU member-states to Russia’s 2014 military conflict with Ukraine. The European countries’ lack of united response and unwillingness to apply severe sanctions (restrictive measures) on Russia in a timely manner is attributed to a constellation of interests of the European countries and Russia in the European energy market.

Published in the printed edition of Baltic Worlds Baltic Worlds 3-4 2015, pp51-61
Published on balticworlds.com on November 19, 2015

article as pdf No Comments on The price of opulence Share
  • Facebook
  • del.icio.us
  • Pusha
  • TwitThis
  • Google
  • LinkedIn
  • Digg
  • Maila artikeln!
  • Skriv ut artikeln!

abstract

This article discusses the reaction of the EU member-states to Russia’s 2014 military conflict with Ukraine. The European countries’ lack of united response and unwillingness to apply severe sanctions (restrictive measures) on Russia in a timely manner is attributed to a constellation of interests of the European countries and Russia in the European energy market. Max Weber’s concept of domination by virtue of a constellation of interests and the related concept of the power triad set the general theoretical framework for the discussion. Statistical data on the energy dependence of the EU member-states on Russia inform it.

Keywords: European energy market, Russia, Ukraine, military conflict, constellation of interests.

The question as to whether the preferences and behavior of power elites in the EU member-states are influenced by the Russian power elite by means of implementing a particular energy policy has not yet received a satisfactory answer. Journalistic accounts of this matter outnumber careful scholarly analyses. Specifically, a publication in The Telegraph blog section on European power elites’ responses to the 2014 Russian military confrontation with Ukraine1 set a stage for a lively public discussion without yet leading to more systematic studies.2

In my reasoning I will use the country as a unit of analysis. By country I mean its power elite — a group of individuals “in positions to make decisions having major consequences”.3 A conventional definition of power says that the party in a position to impose its will on the other party despite the latter’s eventual resistance has power.4 The power holder changes the behavior of the other parties so they start to further the former’s interests. If Russia manages to change the preferences and policies of European countries in a manner beneficial to Russia then de facto this country has power. In particular, a demonstration of Russia’s power refers to some desirable reactions of the EU member-states secured by Russia to Russia’s role in the 2014 military conflict with Ukraine. The EU member-states’ unwillingness to impose severe sanctions on Russia serves the interests of the latter.

The purpose of this article is to explain Russia’s upper hand in relationships with EU member-states by the existence of a constellation of interests of Russia and the EU member-states in the European market for natural gas. The unveiling of Russia’s power requires a re-examination of conventional perceptions of the market as a constraint on a power holder’s discretion, namely in international relationships. Under particular circumstances that are arguably present in the European energy market (and in the national and regional markets in Russia5) the market becomes a pillar of domination instead of being a liberating force. Domination refers to the situation when power is exercised “repeatedly, systematically, and to the detriment of the dominated agent”.6

Techniques of power

Force as a technique of power involves “the creation of physical obstacles restricting the freedom of another”.7 In international politics the use of force amounts to a direct military invasion. Russia used its military force against Georgia (in 2008) and Ukraine while staying clear of relying on this technique of power in its relationships with the EU member-states.

Are the European countries coerced into adapting a softer position with regard to Russia’s use of force against Ukraine? Coercion makes the use of force or the other negative sanctions optional. The coerced actor has a choice, however restricted this choice may be: either he or she obeys or the coercing actor applies negative sanctions.8 Russia’s willingness to cut natural gas supplies was demonstrated in January 2009 during unresolved payment disputes with Ukraine. Russia nevertheless values its reputation as a reliable natural gas supplier to the European Union and keeps repeating that it has never cut natural gas deliveries to its Western customers at will.

Maybe Russia manipulates the EU member-states? The technique of manipulation works through the limitation or selective determination of “the [manipulated] subject’s information supply, e.g. by withholding pertinent information not easily available to the subject from other sources”.9 The Russian power elite has managed to impose tight control over the mass media, a key vehicle for disseminating information. This control was initially asserted at the national level10 and, more recently, at the international level too — with the emergence of Russia Today, a global TV network heavily subsidized by the Russian government. Russia’s capacity to withhold pertinent information at the international level remains limited, however. Russia Today faces competition from a number of other, more established global TV networks.

Does Russia silence criticisms of its internal and foreign politics with the help of corruption? In this context corruption as a particular technique of power involves attempts to cause a decision maker to breach ethical and/or legal rules, which he or she is otherwise expected to follow, in the power holder’s interests.11 In the case of corruption obedience pays: the corrupt decision maker receives a pecuniary compensation for deviating from the prescribed course of action. In contrast to force, coercion and manipulation, the dominated agent (the decision maker) has positive incentives for aligning his or her interests with those of the power holder (the agent offering the bribe). The use of corruption by members of the Russian power elite to promote their interests cannot be excluded.12 There are precedents when the Russian power elite hired former high-ranking European officials offering them lucrative jobs, probably in recognition of their contribution to the promotion of Russia’s interests.13 Nevertheless, the use of corruption can hardly explain the persistent and widespread refusal of the European countries to take a more critical and tougher stance on Russia’s actions. The mean 2013 Transparency International Corruption perception index for the EU member-states is 63.6 out of 100 (Russia has the score of 28; the lower the score, the higher the perceived level of corruption), which suggests a relatively low level of corruption in the operation of government.14

This article aims to explore whether an often overlooked technique of power, namely, domination by virtue of a constellation of interests in the market, sheds new light on the European response to Russia’s internal and foreign policy, especially in its “near abroad” (Russia’s policy toward Ukraine is considered to be a case in point). Weber sets domination by virtue of authority, a well-researched topic in political sociology and political science, against domination by virtue of a constellation of interests without providing much detail. He simply notes that “because of the very absence of rules, domination which originates in the market… may be felt to be much more oppressive than an authority in which the duties of obedience are set out clearly and expressly”.15 I will focus more specifically on a possible constellation of interests of Russia and the EU member-states in the natural gas market.

The use of this technique of power involves reliance on the market but requires that the power holder creates structural imbalances that undermine the principles of free competition. The interests of the parties transacting in the non-clearing market form a constellation, which does not exclude one party having the upper hand and imposing its will on the others. If a rational agent acts under market constraints designed and imposed by the power holder, then the former has an interest in accepting the latter’s upper hand. The dominated agent’s gain is positive. Its other alternatives prove to be poorer in the circumstances. A similar observation applies to an agent that does not deal with the power holder in a direct manner, but transacts with the first dominated agent. The second agent is dominated by the power holder as well, but also receives a positive gain. At the end of the day all the parties involved have interest in maintaining the status quo, i.e. the domination of one of them. The dominated parties are better off in not criticizing the power holder than in challenging the latter and the system that it created.

My working hypothesis is that the stance of an EU member-state on the issue of the imposition of sanctions (restrictive measures) on Russia in the context of this country’s military conflict with Ukraine in 2014 will depend on the scope of the EU member-state’s reliance on natural gas supplies from Russia and the EU member-state’s position in intra-European trade. Natural gas supplies from Russia serve as a proxy for direct contacts between the power holder and the dominated agent. The indirect contacts are operationalized with the help of intra-European trade statistics. A country that does not buy natural gas directly from Russia may nevertheless benefit from having access to goods and services produced by the key customers of Russian natural gas. In other words, the interests of Russia as the key supplier of natural gas, its European customers and customers of products made with the help of Russian energy supplies are expected to form a constellation. This hypothesis will be formally tested using statistical data after I confront the concept of domination by virtue of a constellation of interests with the prevailing accounts of the European energy market at a theoretical level in the two next subsections.

Markets versus empires

There are two popular approaches to theorizing the situation in the European energy market. The “Markets and Institutions” approach is derived from economic liberalism; it emphasizes the importance of energy markets and multilateral cooperation in international energy relations. The “Regions and Empires” approach is, in contrast, based on economic nationalist principles. It depicts international energy relations as a competition between blocks of states over the control of energy resources and energy markets”.16 The first approach places emphasis on the invisible hand of the market and its role in resource allocation. The second approach highlights the visible hand of the people in control of governments, i.e. the power elites.

The scholarly discourse on energy policies in general and European energy policies in particular is currently framed in the “either-or” terms. Either the invisible hand of the market guides energy supplies or the visible hand of government or large corporations’ shareholders17 takes precedence over the market play. The two hands operate independently from each other. As a matter of fact, the invisible hand of the market is believed to make the visible hand of government unnecessary and redundant and vice versa.

Predictions as to the situation in the European energy market made on the basis of the “Market and Institutions” approach sound overly optimistic. Even if the market falls short of the perfectly competitive ideal, it still has the capacity for self-corrections. The existence of a monopoly or oligopoly18 (because the European market for natural gas has three key suppliers, Russian Gazprom, Norwegian Statoil and Algerian Sonatrach) does not necessarily mean that a monopolist or an oligopolist is able to impose his or her will on the other market participants.

First, all market participants win something: they receive a positive utility. Advocates of the “Market and Institutions” approach consider irrelevant the fact that a rent generated by a transaction might be unequally distributed.

Second, agents acting in an imperfectly competitive market develop a significant degree of mutual dependence. The European customers might depend on Gazprom, but Gazprom also depends on them. “Russia… find[s] [herself] substantially financially dependent on Europe, on the revenues generated by [her] export of oil and natural gas. Gazprom receives about 65 % of its revenues from Europe, and directly generated 8 % of Russian GDP in 2005”.19 Mutual dependence causes a strategic convergence of interests of Russia and the European countries that even major geopolitical conflicts do not undermine. The European countries continued to supply Russia (in the shape of its predecessor, the Soviet Union) pipes, binding tapes, drills and bits even during the economic embargo following the Afghanistan invasion, and credit terms remained favorable.20 Advocates of the “Market and Institutions” approach see it as a proof of the prevalence of “win-win” transactions in the market, however imperfect competition might be.

Third, in the conditions of restricted supply customers may also decide to form a countervailing monopsony. Proposals to move in this direction are being actively debated in the European countries21 without yet leading to practical changes, however. The existence of a bilateral monopoly limits structural preconditions for capturing the rent generated by a transaction and increases the importance of the strategies used by the parties involved. A party’s bargaining power refers to its ability to select the strategy of negotiation to maximize the share of the rent captured by the party.

Dowding differentiates luck and power in this respect.22 Luck derives from structural factors that enable one party to impose its will on the others. Narrowly defined power refers to a strategic component. The strategic component of power involves selecting a strategy, a technique for imposing one’s will on the others.

Are Russia’s positions of power in the European energy market due to luck alone? I argue that the structural imbalances that currently characterize this market have to be made endogenous to our models. In addition to exploiting its position of power to its advantage, Russia also invests heavily in infrastructural projects that will further enhance structural components of its power (namely, the Blue Stream, Nord Stream and South Stream pipelines23). And European countries seem to be willing to accept Russia’s continuous expansion in the European energy market.

The recent developments in the New Institutional Economics, the NIE, help better differentiate the market for natural gas from the other segments of the European energy market. The NIE add a third element to the dichotomy of the market and the organization (government being one of them): hybrid forms or relational contracting. “The parties to [hybrid modes of contracting] maintain autonomy, but the contract is mediated by an elastic contracting mechanism”.24 Claude Ménard describes the contracting mechanism in the terms of authority, “that is, the conscious and deliberate delegation of the capacity to make a subset of decisions to a body in charge of coordinating”.25 The important role that authority as a particular case of power plays in the operation of hybrids deserves mentioning. The visible hand of authority complements the invisible hand of the market.

Transactions between the key oil and gas companies in the European Union and Russia take the form of long-term contracts with in-built mechanisms of adjustments (“authority”) to external shocks. Attempts to increase the share of transactions on the spot market (these transactions involve no long-term commitment of any party) have been unsuccessful so far, especially in the natural gas market. Gazprom clearly prefers signing long-term contracts and strategic bilateral agreements with its European customers.26

The preference for relational contracting has an economic rationale. The New Institutional economists explain the choice between alternative forms, the market, the firm and relational contracting, in the terms of asset specificity.27 Specific assets cannot be redeployed without a loss of value. They produce the most when being employed only in a particular transaction. The specificity of assets has several components: site specificity (bilateral dependency results from location constraints), physical specificity (assets that use specific inputs such as customized computer programs), dedicated assets (large investments made for satisfying the needs of a particular customer), human assets (firm-specific knowledge and skills), brand name capital and temporal specificity (lock-in among parties involved in a technological process).28

The three first components are present in the case of the natural gas market (the degree of asset specificity in the market for oil is also high, but tends to be lower than in the natural gas market). Major natural gas fields in Europe are located on Russian territory, which makes its delivery to non-European markets more expensive (“site specificity”). The cheapest way to transport natural gas over the long distances is in compressed form through a large diameter pipeline (“physical specificity”). Its construction requires substantial investments (“dedicated assets”).29 The development of the market for liquefied natural gas (LNG) also requires investment in specific assets (cargo ships and terminals).

Hybrid forms incorporate power only in a weak form: they involve delegating a “subset” of decisions, whereas the rest of their activities are still coordinated by the conventional visible hand, i.e. the Russian government in the case of Gazprom. Parties maintain their autonomy and avoid relationships of subordination. So in the end, the concept of hybrids is of little assistance in explaining the eventual transformation of the market into a tool for enhancing power. We observe just the opposite: how authority as a particular type of power relationships helps maximize the output of specific assets in the market environment.

In contrast to the optimism of the “Market and Institutions” approach, the “Regions and Empires” approach leads to mostly pessimistic conclusions. Specifically, the latter approach predicts that power play will take place of market play. In market play, all parties involved win. In power play there is one winner whereas the others lose. The winning party achieves this outcome at the expense of the other parties.30

When applied to the European energy market, the “Regions and Empires” framework suggests that Russia will use energy supplies as a lever for securing unilateral gains, pecuniary or geopolitical. “From the perspective of ‘Regions and Empires’, the EU’s energy relations with Russia (and other third states) are understood as a geopolitical power struggle”.31 Advocates of this approach produce numerous examples that, they believe, confirm its validity. The Soviet Union entered to the European energy market in the 1960s. Initially supplies of oil had an irregular character. For instance, the Soviet Union sold crude oil in exchange for various products that the Soviet economy failed to produce in sufficient quantities. In order to enter the market, the Soviet Union set ask prices sometimes two times lower than the market price at that time.32 In other words, the European countries had power over the Soviet Union as a new entrant to the European energy market. The situation later changed. The Soviet Union learned how to increase its power and to be less dependent on the market. Gaidar claims that the Soviet leadership in the 1970s actively participated in manipulating the European crude oil market by contributing to the prolongation of the “oil war” of Arab countries against the Western countries. Relevant operations of its ally, the People’s Liberation Front of Palestine, were instrumental in this regard.33

The Soviet Union was also an exclusive supplier of oil and natural gas to the East European market (now a part of the European market). This country was able to impose additional — mostly geopolitical and political — conditions for receiving its oil and gas. For example, “in exchange for a guarantee on energy exports the Soviet Union may demand that Eastern Europe as a whole follows a cautious line on economic reform, more in tune with its own conservative program” or limits contacts with the West European countries.34 At that time, however, the energy weapon played a secondary role in Russia’s repertoire of techniques of power, supplementing rather than substituting for force (military presence and control).

Russia, which succeeded the Soviet Union’s role as a key supplier of oil and natural gas to the European market, strengthened its position of power even further. Now this country imposes conditions for receiving its oil and gas not only on East European countries, but on West European countries as well. An analysis of voting patterns of a Parliamentary Assembly of the Council of Europe (PACE) resolution and a PACE recommendation criticizing Russia’s military conflict with Georgia August 2008 show that Russia succeeded in demanding that customers of its energy products take a more neutral stance.35 The course of action chosen by Russia less than one year later, in January 2009, further confirms arguments of advocates of the “Regions and Empires” approach. Russia used cuts in gas supplies to Ukraine to strengthen its bargaining position in a dispute with this country.

The representation of the two prevailing approaches in the opposite terms certainly facilitates the understanding of the underlying rationale: the market and power relationships are the alternative foundations of the European energy policy. At the same time this black and white take on the issue does not allow a more nuanced picture: namely, can the two hands, the invisible hand of the market and the visible hand of government, operate in concert instead of one excluding the other? Speaking more practically, can the power elite of a large energy supplier transform the market into a tool for enhancing its power without renouncing the centrality of the market? If the answer to this research and practical question is affirmative, then a combination of the “Regions and Empires” approach and the “Market and Institutions” approach may provide a better fit to the observed patterns in European energy policies.

Market-based empires

The concept of the power triad paves a way to considering both structural and strategic components of power within a single theoretical framework.36 This analytical tool aims to highlight the eventual transformation of strategic components of power into its structural components and vice versa. Russia’s efforts to embed the European natural gas market into an infrastructure that facilitates the further strengthening of its positions of power result from conscious choices made by the Russian power elite. The European countries’ power elites also make conscious choices when accepting Russia’s expansion: in 2011 Russia provided 21.23% of total energy supplies (natural gas, crude oil and solid fuels combined) to the EU member-states, 3.44% more than in 2004 (Table 1). The awareness that a high degree of dependence on energy supplies from Russia can be and actually has been used by this country as a tool for promoting its geopolitical objectives is outweighed by some other considerations, apparently. The concept of the power triad helps unveil these additional considerations.

TABLE 1 See here>>

The power triad includes three agents: a gatekeeper (C), an agent enjoying a structural advantage (A), for instance, facing limited competition, and an agent transacting with A, who has no structural advantage (B). C plays a key role within the power triad. C erects barriers — technical, institutional, geographical or financial — to market entry. With their help C controls entry to the market. To get access to the market, A must accept C’s conditions: either to pay the price of the entry ticket or to further C’s interests in some other manner. In the exchange, A gets the privilege of acting with fewer competitors: only few of them manage to enter the market. Many (A’-type agents) saw their access to the market denied as a result of restrictions imposed by C. B enters the market without restrictions, but has to buy goods or services from A, who either charges a higher price in conditions of imperfect competition or demands from B other favors that further A’s interests. It has to be noted, however, that B has an interest in buying goods or services from A since the available alternatives are poorer in the terms of their utility.

C benefits most from the existence of the power triad. C decides the number of A-type agents to be admitted to the market, maximizing the rent that he or she captures. The barriers represent a structural component of C’s power. C’s decisions with respect to the ratios of the number of A-type agents to the number of B-type agents and to the number of A’-type agents refer to a strategic component of C’s power. A also captures a rent as a result of acting in the conditions of limited competition (a part of A’s profits is subsequently transferred to C in compensation for the latter’s gatekeeping). B buys goods and services that he or she would not otherwise be able to buy at a better price or to buy at all. C, A and B maintain their formal autonomy. Neither A nor B enters into relationship of formal subordination to C. C imposes his or her will on A and B “from behind the scenes”. C’s activities remain mostly invisible for A and especially for B (B does not enter in direct contact with C). As a result of this lack of formalization, A’s and B’s duties of obedience are not set out clearly and expressly, as observed by Weber.

C, A and B all gain from participating in the power triad, however unequal their gains may be. C’s, A’s and B’s interests form a constellation in the market with restricted access, which lays the foundation for C’s and A’s domination by virtue of a constellation of interests. This constellation contributes to the strengthening of C’s and, to a lesser extent, A’s power. C’s power within the power triad is embodied in two hands: the visible hand of the gatekeeper and the invisible hand of the market with structural imbalances created by the gatekeeper. A needs one hand, invisible, to impose his or her will on B. In other words, in order to make sense of how the power triad works, one needs to combine assumptions of both the “Markets and Institutions” approach and the “Regions and Empires” approach.

Compared with more conventional models of power relationships, the power triad may seem to some as an excessively complicated construct. For instance, Dowding insists that by focusing on “a simple bilateral bargain between state actors and business” we could gain as much insight. According to him, the introduction of a third party into the model is simply unnecessary.37 Do we really need to take into account all three actors, C, A and B, when discussing power reproduced and enhanced through the market?

If one considers “a simple bilateral bargain”, then the set of options available to its parties remains an exogenous factor to the transaction. Dowding agrees that “changing the choice situation of people is… an important way of altering their individual and collective power” without showing how the choice situation can be subject to a bilateral bargain.38 To say that we have the available options “by virtue of the circumstances”, as Dowding suggests, is to acknowledge their exogenous character. The concept of the power triad aims to show how the choice situation can be changed and by whom. C, the gatekeeper, determines the choice situations of A and B. This concept also explains the acceptance of C’s and A’s power despite the unequal distribution of gains from the transaction. Even B, whose gain turns to be the smallest, does not object to the existence of the power triad.

The 2014 Ukrainian crisis

A study of the reaction of the European countries to the 2014 Russian military confrontation with Ukraine further illustrates the usefulness of the concept of the power triad. The crisis started after Ukrainian protesters in Kiev ousted Viktor Yanukovich, a pro-Russian president, from office in February 2014. Profiting from the weakness of the Ukrainian state at these turbulent times, Russia first seized Crimea and then started to support pro-Russian separatists in Eastern Ukraine (in the regions of Donetsk and Lugansk) supplying them with arms, including heavy, financial and human resources (Russia sent “volunteers” and military personnel to fight on the separatists’ side).

Details of the Ukrainian crisis and its internal dynamics are of no concern here. I will concentrate instead on the reaction of the European countries to Russia’s role in the crisis. One could have expected an immediate and strong condemnation of the violation of Ukraine’s territorial integrity by Russia. First, Ukraine is geographically a part of Europe and has land borders with the four EU member-states (Poland, the Slovak Republic, Hungary and Romania). Second, one of the reasons behind the 2013—2014 Ukrainian protests refers to the desire for greater integration with the European Union.39 Third, the Russian involvement undermined a principle that has historically underpinned the European geopolitical constructions, namely, the balance of Europe. “The balance of Europe primarily meant the impossibility of the strongest state laying down the law to any other state”.40 Fourth, Russia’s role in the crisis highlighted the need for enforcing (as opposed to merely declaring) norms that restrict the use of force in international relationships (namely, Chapter VII “Action with respect to threats to the peace, breaches of the peace, and acts of aggression” of the Charter of the United Nations).41

Table 2 see here>>

The European countries responded by imposing individual sanctions (restrictive measures) on a number of mid-level Russian officials and leaders of the separatists.42 So called “sectorial” sanctions, i.e. sanctions affecting Russian banking system and industries, were considered at a very advanced stage in the military conflict. The “sectorial” sanctions were not consistently and fully applied, however.

The issue of sanctions was a source of controversies and debates among the European power elites. Instead of producing a united and univocal response to Russia’s seizure of Crimea and her destabilizing role in Eastern Ukraine, the European Union turned out to be divided among a group of countries favoring a “soft” response and a group of countries supporting tougher measures against Russia. Experts of Open Europe, a European think-thank, labelled the former groups as “Doves” and the latter group as “Hawks” producing an ordinal-level assessment of the intensity of support for tougher sanctions on Russia (Table 1).43 Can the variation in the level of support for tougher sanctions on Russia be explained in the terms of the European countries’ dependency on energy supplies from this country? Does the concept of the power triad shed additional light on this issue?

A power triad exists in the European natural gas market. Within this power triad, Russia, C, controls access to its pipelines delivering gas to the European customers represented by national energy companies. As a condition of access to a reliable source of relatively cheap energy (compared to the other sources), C expects that A will further C’s interests, pecuniary or non-pecuniary, including geopolitical. The European energy companies with privileged access to the pipeline, A, have a structural advantage over the national companies with no direct access to the pipeline, A’. As a result, the national economies of the European countries with direct access to the pipeline get a competitive advantage over the other European national economies. A produces goods and services at relatively lower costs (the price of gas is directly or indirectly — via the price of electricity — included in cost calculations for most goods and services), which makes them more competitive in the European market. Consumers of these goods and services, B, benefit too: they buy products for a better price (compared with domestically produced goods and services),44 all other things being equal.

C, A and B all receive a positive gain. Their interests form a constellation in the European natural gas market embedded in the network of pipelines either inherited from the Soviet era or built recently. In these circumstances C’s power has both components, structural and strategic (the latter refers to Russia’s efforts to set prices in a selective manner in relation to how a particular customer furthers Russia’s interests and to promote new infrastructural projects that will further enhance its gatekeeping ability).

If the European natural gas market operates as the power triad so described, then several predictions can be formulated and empirically tested. Namely, the bigger the share of natural gas supplied from Russia in a country’s total net supplies, the lower the level of support for tougher sanctions on Russia (in other words, A’s and C’s interests tend to be positively associated). Also, the bigger the share of natural gas supplied from Russia in a country’s total net supplies, the more positive the country’s trade balance (C’s, A’s and B’s interests tend to be associated). B buys A’s goods and services, thus a negative trade balance serves as a proxy for playing B’s role.

To test these predictions, I ran several OLS regressions of a EU member-state’s level of support for tougher sanctions on Russia on the coefficient of its dependence on total energy supplies from Russia, the share of natural gas supplies from Russia in net total supplies, the total trade turnover (export and import combined) with Russia as a percentage of GDP, GDP per capita, the intra-European Union trade balance without raw materials as a percentage of GDP45 and several dummy variables specifying the European country’s geographical location.46 I used 3-year average values of the ratio-level variables (2010-2012) to eliminate possible fluctuations and the impact of the inauguration of Nord Stream’s first line in November 2011.47

The European country’s stance on the sanctions is used as a proxy for Russia’s interests as C within the power triad. Only a non-pecuniary, geopolitical dimension of these interests is taken into account in my model. I operationalize the degree of the European country’s dependence on energy supplies from Russia through two variables, the aggregate coefficient of total energy dependence and the share of natural gas supplies from Russia. The higher their values, the more chances that a particular European country plays A’s role within the power triad. The European country’s trade turnover as a percentage of its GDP represents the other dimension of its economic dependence on Russia. It should be noted that of these three indicators of the European country’s economic dependence on Russia, the share of natural gas supplies refers to the most specific assets (pipelines, storage facilities and the other transport infrastructure) whereas the trade turnover relates to the least specific.

The intra-EU trade balance serves to operationalize A’s and B’s interests: A’s interests if the particular country’s balance is positive and B’s interests in the opposite case. A’s and B’s interests have a pecuniary dimension in my model. A and B’s motivation is pecuniary and their choices rational in the circumstances. A control variable — GDP per capita — is also entered to test the assumption of A’s pecuniary interests.

Table 2 summarizes results of the regression analysis. Models 1 and 2 show that, taken separately, neither the coefficient of total energy dependence nor the share of natural gas supplies from Russia explains the variation in the level of support for tougher sanctions on Russia. The addition of the trade turnover with Russia in Model 3 does not change the situation. Outcomes of the regression become statistically significant with the addition of several dummy variables specifying the European country’s geographical location in Model 4: namely, the North European countries and the countries sharing land borders with Ukraine support tougher sanctions to a greater extent than the other countries. The entry of GDP per capita significantly improves the quality of the model (Model 5) and makes the impact of the share of natural gas supplies from Russia significant. The control variable, GDP per capita, “is discovered to be the mediating factor through which an independent variable [the share of natural gas supplies] has its effect on a dependent variable [the stance on sanctions on Russia]”.48 This finding turns out to be relevant to my argument about A’s pragmatic interest in accepting C’s power.

The uncertainly as to where to place the Baltic States (Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia) — some sources include them in Northern Europe, whereas the other consider them to be a part of Eastern Europe — led me to run regressions using two versions of the dummy variables for Northern and Eastern Europe. Model 6 is identical to Model 5 except in relation to the Baltic States (now included in Eastern Europe). The negative impact of the share of natural gas supplies becomes even stronger. At the same time the positive impact of sharing land borders with Ukraine almost disappears: the original relationship is “shown to be false through the introduction of a test variable”,49 GDP per capita. In these circumstances I decided not to enter the two dummy variables for countries with common borders with either Ukraine or Russia in Model 7. Instead, I entered the intra-EU27 trade balance. This variable has a negative — and marginally statistically significant50 — impact on the dependent variable. In other words, the European countries with a positive intra-EU27 trade balance tend to adapt a softer position on sanctions on Russia. A converts its privileged access to Russian gas pipelines into competitive advantages in the intra-European trade. B, a customer of A’s products, has a negative trade balance. B buys more products from A, but receive relatively fewer benefits from the existence of the power triad than C and A. B-type countries tend to concentrate in Southern Europe: Italy, Spain, Portugal and Greece all have negative intra-EU27 trade balances. Model 7 explains slightly more than 43% of the variation in the European country’s stance on sanctions on Russia.

The price of comfort
and opulence

In the final account, the hypothesis about the existence of the power triad in the European natural gas market turns out to be tentatively confirmed (it would be necessary to run more comprehensive tests using a longer list of indicators, especially with respect to B’s interests, before making any definitive claims). Russia, C, provides European countries with relatively cheap natural gas. Compared with the other sources of energy (namely crude oil and coal), the market for natural gas can be manipulated relatively more easily since its infrastructure includes highly specific assets (pipelines and storage facilities) that may possibly be transformed into a structural component of power.51 Russia’s power elite seized this opportunity by developing a second component of power, strategic. The strategic component of Russia’s power consists in getting the key European markets “wired” to Russian pipelines and in using the strategy of gatekeeping, i.e. providing privileged access to the pipelines only to those customers who willingly further the Russian power elite’s interests.

The reaction of the EU member-states to Russia’s military confrontation with Ukraine in 2014 is a case in point. The Russian power elite got what its members wanted, i.e. the refusal of the European power elites to impose tougher sanctions on Russia. The concept of the power triad shows that fears that Russia will arbitrarily cut gas supplies to European customers or, even worse, use military force against them have little basis. C has an interest in building and maintaining the reputation of a reliable supplier provided that A and B accept C’s rules of the game. C has power by virtue of a constellation of A’s and B’s interests with C’s interests. C does not “buy” or corrupt A in a conventional sense of this word. C simply changes A’s and B’s choice situation in such a manner that they pragmatically decide to support C’s endeavors.

The concept of the power triad also suggests that it would be a mistake to explain the European response to the Ukrainian crisis in the terms of bilateral relationships only. The interests of European countries, including those outside the reach of Russian pipelines (at least so far), form a constellation. Focusing on bilateral relationships overshadows the fact that B-type agents, customers of goods and services produced by the countries with privileged access to Russian pipelines, lose in relative, but not in absolute terms.

Neither A nor B has an interest in changing the status quo, i.e. in taking serious steps undermining the power triad in the European energy market. In these circumstances the considerations of “mutual solidarity”52 and even duty (the United Kingdom accepted the role of guarantor of Ukraine’s unity and territorial integrity in 1994)53 become irrelevant. A’s and B’s pragmatic interests turn to be more powerful drivers of their behavior. It means that the power triad will likely continue to exist in the European energy market. ≈

 

references

1
As of the publication date of this article, the military conflict is not over. Despite several efforts to “freeze” it (they resulted in two Minsk agreements brokered by Germany and France in September 2014 and February 2015), a potential for escalation continues to exist as long as Russia has not been forced to pay a full price for its violation of Ukraine’s sovereignty. An agreement dated September 2015 on the extension of an existing natural gas pipeline between Russia and Germany, Nord Stream-2 (see also End note 13), suggests that prospects for making Russia pay the full price remain uncertain. However, since the confrontation started in 2014 and the data used in the paper do not reflect the most recent developments, I will use the term “2014 military conflict”.

2
Matts Persson, “The EU remains a long way off agreeing tougher sanctions on Russia”, The Telegraph’s blogs, April 16, 2014. Accessed July 15, 2014, http://blogs.telegraph.co.uk/finance/matspersson/100027053/the-eu-remains-a-long-way-off-agreeing-tougher-sanctions-on-russia/.

3
Charles Wright Mills, The Power Elite (New York: Oxford University Press, 1957), 4.

4
Max Weber, Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretative Sociology (New York: Bedminster Press, 1968 [1922]), 53.

5
Anton Oleinik, Market as a Weapon: The Socio-Economic Machinery of Dominance in Russia (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers, 2010); Anton Oleinik, “Benefits of entry control: the Russian case”, Post-Communist Economies, 27 (2015).

6
Thomas E.Wartenberg, The Forms of Power: From Domination to Transformation (Philadelphia, PH: Temple University Press, 1990), 117.

7
Dennis H. Wrong, Power: Its Forms, Bases and Uses (New York: Harper Colophon Books, 1980), 24.

8
James S. Coleman, Foundations of Social Theory (Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1990), 71.

9
Valeri G. Ledyaev, Power: A Conceptual Analysis (Commack, NY: Nova Science Publishers, 1997), 191.

10
Andrew Wilson, Virtual Politics: Faking Democracy in the Post-Soviet World (New Haven, CT and London: Yale University Press, 2005).

11
Geoffrey M. Hodgson and Shuxia Jiang, “The Economics of Corruption and the Corruption of Economics: An Institutionalist Perspective”, Journal of Economic Issues, 41 (2007), 1053.

12
Ararat L. Osipian, “Corrupt Organizational Hierarchies in the Former Soviet Bloc”, Transition Studies Review 17 (2010).

13
For instance, Gerhard Schröder, a former Chancellor of the Federal Republic of Germany, is a member of the Shareholder Committee of Nord Stream AG, the operator of a natural gas pipeline directly connecting Russia to its largest European consumer, Germany, through the Baltic Sea. Accessed July, 16, 2014, http://www.nord-stream.com/about-us/our-management/.

14
Transparency International, “Corruption Perception Index 2013,” accessed October 8, 2014, http://cpi.transparency.org/cpi2013/in_detail/.

15
Weber, Economy and Society, 946.

16
Anke Schmidt-Felzmann, “EU Member States’ Energy Relations with Russia: Conflicting Approaches to Securing Natural Gas Supplies”, Geopolitics, 16 (2011), 575; see also Aad Correljé and Coby Van der Linde, “Energy supply security and geopolitics: A European perspective”, Energy Policy, 34 (2006) and Dominique Finon and Catherine Locatelli, “Russian and European gas interdependence: Could contractual trade channel geopolitics?” Energy Policy, 36 (2008).

17
In the case of Gazprom, the Russian government holds more than half, 50.23%, of this corporation’s shares. Accessed July 16, 2014, http://www.gazprom.com/investors/stock.

18
Thijs Jansen, Arie Van Lier, Arjen Van Witteloostuijn, and Tim Boon von Ochssée, “A modified Cournot model of the natural gas market in the European Union: Mixed-motives delegation in a politicized environment”, Energy Policy, 41 (2012).

19
Richard E. Ericson, “Eurasian Natural Gas Pipelines: The Political Economy of Network Interdependence”, Eurasian Geography and Economics, 50 (2009), 35.

20
Rowland Maddock, “Energy and Integration: The Logic of Interdependence in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe”, Journal of Common Market Studies, 19 (1980), 28—9; see also Mohsin S. Hashim, “Power-loss or power-transition? Assessing the limits of using the energy sector in reviving Russia’s geopolitical stature”, Communist and Post-Communist Studies, 43 (2010), 272 for a similar argument regarding the current situation.

21
Ericson, “Eurasian Natural Gas Pipelines”, 40.

22
Keith Dowding, Power (Minneapolis: MN: University of Minnesota Press, 1996), Chapter 3.

23
The South Stream project is now put on hold. Russia considers developing an alternative project with similar parameters, Turkish Stream, however.

24
Oliver E. Williamson, “Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives”, Administrative Science Quarterly, 36 (1991), 271.

25
Claude Ménard, “Theory of Organizations: The Diversity of Arrangements in a Developed Market Economy”, in The Institutional Economics of Russia’s Transformation, ed. A. Oleinik (Aldershot: Ashgate, 2005), 96.

26
Finon and Locatelli, “Russian and European gas interdependence”, 430; Correljé and Van der Linde, “Energy supply security and geopolitics”, 540.

27
Williamson, “Comparative Economic Organization”.

28
Claude Ménard, “Transaction Cost Economics: From the Coase Theorem to Empirical Studies”, in The Institutional Economics of Russia’s Transformation, ed. A. Oleinik (Aldershot: Ashgate, 2005), 55—6.

29
Ericson, “Eurasian Natural Gas Pipelines”, 29.

30
The “Market and Institutions” approach can be described in the terms of “pure collaboration” games, whereas the “Regions and Empires” approach refers to zero-sum games. In the “pure collaboration” game the players win or lose together, having identical preferences regarding the income. The zero-sum game represents their opposite, see Thomas S. Schelling, The Strategy of Conflict (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1960), 84.

31
Schmidt-Felzmann, “EU Member States’ Energy Relations with Russia”, 575; see also Finon and Locatelli, “Russian and European gas interdependence”, 425 and Correljé and Van der Linde, “Energy supply security and geopolitics”, 536.

32
Egor T. Gaidar, Gibel’ imperii: uroki dlya sovremennoi Rossii [Collapse of an Empire: Lessons for Modern Russia] (Moscow: ROSSPEN, 2006), 109.

33
Gaidar, Gibel’ imperii, 191. One of the objectives of Russia’s military operation in Syria that started in October 2015 refers to a similar rationale, arguably.

34
Maddock, “Energy and Integration”, 34.

35
Bryon Moraski and Magda Giucanu, “European Reactions to the 2008 Georgian–Russian War: Assessing the Impact of Gas Dependence”, Studies in Comparative International Development, 48 (2013), 432—456. As of 2014, the PACE includes 28 national delegations of the EU member-states and 18 national delegations from the European countries that are not members of the EU.

36
This concept is discussed in detail in my two monographs: Oleinik, Market as a Weapon, and Anton Oleinik, The Invisible Hand of Power: An Economic Theory of Gatekeeping ((London and New York: Routledge, 2015).

37
Keith Dowding, “Review of ‘Market as a Weapon: The Socio-Economic Machinery of Dominance in Russia’”, Contemporary Sociology: A Journal of Reviews, 43 (2014), 566—7.

38
Dowding, Power, 24.

39
Ilko Kucheriv Democratic Initiatives Foundation, “Vid Maidanu-Taboru do Maidanu-Sichi: shcho zminylosya?” [From Maidan-Tabir to Maidan-Sich: common and diverse characteristics], February 3, 2014. Accessed July 17, 2014, http://dif.org.ua/ua/publications/press-relizy/vid-mchi-sho-zminilos.htm.

40
Michel Foucault, Security, Territory, Population. Lectures at the Collège de France, 1977—1978, translated by G. Burchell (Basingstoke and New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2007), 299. The applicability of the balance of Europe principle in today’s circumstances is contested. See for example: Dugin, Alexandr “Proekt ‘Imperiya’”, Profil’, 34 (2008), Mearsheimer, John, “Why the Ukraine Crisis Is the West’s Fault,” Foreign Affairs, 93 (2014), 77—78. http://itar-tass.com/politika/1291203.

41
On March 27, 2014 Ukraine secured a resolution of the United Nations General Assembly titled “Territorial integrity of Ukraine” (100 votes in favor to 11 against, with 58 abstentions) that calls on member-States to “desist and refrain” from actions aimed at disrupting Ukraine’s national unity and territorial integrity, including by modifying its borders through the threat or use of force.

42
The Council of the European Union took a series of decisions with respect to the restrictive measures “directed against certain persons, entities and bodies in view of the situation in Ukraine”. Full texts of these decisions are available at the EUR-Lex web-site. Accessed July 17, 2014, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/search.html?instInvStatus=ALL&text=%22restrictive%20measures%22%20ukraine&qid=1404774373429&DTS_DOM=PUBLISHED_IN_OJ&textScope=ti-te&type=advanced&lang=en&SUBDOM_INIT=PUBLISHED_IN_OJ&DTS_SUBDOM=PUBLISHED_IN_OJ.

43
Open Europe, “Divided we stand: Where do EU states stand on further sanctions on Russia?”, April 16, 2014. Accessed July 17, 2014, http://www.openeurope.org.uk/Article/Page/en/LIVE?id=19876&page=FlashAnalysis.

44
Which does not exclude that B overpays for goods and services compared to the situation when A produces them in conditions of perfect competition.

45

The distribution of these variables was visually inspected prior to regression analysis. This “eyeballing” suggested that the normality of distribution condition was not significantly violated.

46
Outcomes of Levene’s Test of Equality of Variances show that the assumption of homogeneity of the variance in the dependent variable, the European country’s stance on sanctions on Russia, is met for all the dummy variables.

47
Croatia joined the European Union in 2013, which explains its exclusion from the present analysis.

48
Earl Babbie and Lucia Benaquisto, Fundamentals of Social Research (Scarborough, ON: Nelson), 436.

49
Babbie and Benaquisto, Fundamentals of Social Research, 434.

50
p=0.13.

51
The entry of the coefficient of total energy dependency into the regression models instead of the share of natural gas supplies from Russia shows that the latter variable has a weaker predictive power: the models’ quality decreases.

52
Schmidt-Felzmann, “EU Member States’ Energy Relations with Russia”.

53
As per Budapest Memorandum on Security Assurances of December 5, 1994. Two other guarantors were the United States and the Russian Federation.

 

  • by Anton Oleinik

    Professor of sociology at Memorial University of Newfoundland (St. John's, Canada) and leading research fellow at the Central Economics and Mathematics Institute of the Russian Academy of Sciences (Moscow, Russia).

  • all contributors
  • Peer-reviewed articles are scientific articles.

    Peer-reviewed articles have all been through a peer-review process. We practice double-blind peer-review. All material is reviewed by two independent specialists at least at post-doc level. A prerequisite for publishing scientific articles in Baltic Worlds is that the article has not already been published in English elsewhere. If an article is simultaneously being considered by another publication, this should be indicated when submitting.

    Would you like to contribute to Baltic Worlds? Click here!